Submission on the Climate Change response
(zero carbon) amendment bill
Submitter: Professor Euan G. Mason
Profile: Euan Mason is a Professor at
the New Zealand School of Forestry, University of Canterbury, where he teaches
silviculture, statistics, modelling, and research methodology. His research interests include forest growth
and yield modelling, tree physiology, and silviculture. He has published numerous peer-reviewed articles
relating to climate change and forestry, and has been employed by government
ministries and political parties to advise them on climate change issues from
time to time. He is a New Zealand
citizen, born in Invercargill. He was educated
at universities in New Zealand and the United States of America.
Introduction
In previous
submissions I outlined New Zealand’s emissions and the failure of our ETS to
make any substantial difference to our greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Our net
emissions increased by 54 % between 1990 and 2016, with agricultural and the energy
sectors contributing 49% and 40% of emissions respectively (MfE, 2018). Our gross GHG emissions are
approximately 80 million tonnes of CO2-e. Clearly our emissions
trading scheme (ETS) has failed so far, and so we need to change it. The
climate change amendment (zero carbon) bill may result in positive change along
with additional mechanisms for New Zealand’s climate change response.
The ETS was
touted as a “cap and trade” scheme, where a cap on allowed emissions is
supposed to be gradually reduced over time, and emitters are “grandfathered” carbon
credits, called “New Zealand Emission Units” (NZUs) for their allowed pollution
which they either submit each year or, if they reduce their pollution below the
cap, they can sell. The price of NZUs dropped substantially late in 2011 when
New Zealanders began to import cheap “hot air” credits (ERUs) from eastern
Europe (Mason, 2013) that represented no real
environmental gain (Alessi & Fujiwara, 2011). The price of these bogus, imported credits
was as low as $0.17, and many New Zealand greenhouse gas (GHG) emitters bought
and surrendered them instead of NZUs in order to meet their obligations. In 2015 the New Zealand government outlawed
the surrendering of imported credits, and this has led to a modest increase in
the price of NZUs. However, that was not
the only flaw in ETS policy, and some of those other flaws are outlined in this
submission.
The case for New Zealand taking action
Few of us
are equipped to understand global climate models, and so we rely on the
integrity of the world’s climate modellers. I have yet to hear any convincing
argument that their integrity is suspect or that their reasoning is flawed, but
I am no expert on climate change models, and so I write this under the
assumption that we have an urgent problem with anthropogenic emissions of
greenhouse gases, particularly CO2, CH4 and N2O.
Generally, on a 100 year time horizon, CH4 is considered to be about
24 times more potent as a greenhouse gas than CO2 and N2O
is rated as 298 times more potent than CO2. If we use a 20 year time horizon, CH4 is about 84
times more potent than CO2.
Some people
argue that because New Zealand has a small population we should not take action
because reducing our emissions will have minimal physical impact. The fallacy
in this argument is of course that any population of 4.5 million people could
make the same claim, yet we all contribute to the problem. Moreover, most
groups of 4.5 million people around the world emit less CO2-e (CO2
equivalents) than New Zealand does. A third reason why this claim is silly is
that our example may speak far more loudly and have a bigger impact on
behaviour of other countries than our proportion of global population.
Recommendation:
New Zealand should continue to make and keep our international climate change
commitments
Agriculture and a fragmented, sector by
sector approach
To translate
our international commitments into domestic action, we have created an
emissions trading scheme (ETS) that is meant to be a cap and trade scheme, but
it does not operate like a cap and trade scheme and its design has so far led
to failure.
New Zealand
has taken a fragmented approach to emissions trading that has greatly reduced
the ETS’s effectiveness. In particular, agriculture, which contributes almost
half our national GHG emissions has no credit surrender requirement and
therefore no incentive to undertake any mitigation activities. The excuse used
for this exception is that “agriculture has no mitigation options” (Hon. Tim
Groser, on several occasions), but that statement is false.
At least two
very effective mitigation options are available to the agricultural
sector. Nitrous oxide emissions comprise
a large minority of agricultural GHGs, and these can be significantly reduced
by more efficient use of fertiliser. In
addition, plenty of erosion prone land currently under grass could be planted
in trees without significant reductions in livestock numbers on our farms. With an effective ETS, many farmers would
then earn money from their mitigation activities. They currently have no
incentive to undertake either of these mitigation options.
Clearly the
agricultural sector could make a large contribution to mitigating its own GHG
emissions, but it has no incentive to do so with current policies. Hill-country
farming would become more profitable if farmers were encouraged to engage in
carbon forestry on land that is relatively unproductive for agriculture, and
competition for land between carbon forestry and farming is unbalanced while
agricultural greenhouse gas emissions attract no penalty.
Methane is
about 84 times worse than carbon dioxide as a greenhouse gas, but it has a much
shorter life in the atmosphere. Currently the international community prefers
to handle this by adopting a 100 year time frame and reducing the relative
effects of methane accordingly. Until such time as we can convince the
international community to change its approach to methane pollution we should
retain the current international accounting scheme for it.
Recommendation:
Agriculture should be brought into the ETS immediately, and all sectors should
be treated equally in the scheme. All GHGs should be treated the same under 100
year estimates of CO2-e.
Bringing
agriculture into the scheme would not solve the ETS’s problems on its own.
There are several other issues that need to be sorted out.
Grandfathering of credits
We can make
rapid progress at mitigating climate change by adopting the simple principle
that those who emit GHGs should either sequester them or pay other people to
sequester them. This principle has been
undermined by ETS policies.
The
government has engaged in a practice labelled “grandfathering”, where polluters
are given credits for “allowed emissions” up to a portion of their actual
emissions and then they have to surrender credits for some of their emissions. The extent of grandfathering has reduced
recently, but “trade-exposed” industries still receive credits for up to 90% of
their emissions. Grandfathered credits
represent no cleaning of the atmosphere and flood the credit market with
credits that are as bogus as “hot air” credits from Eastern Europe (Mason, 2013). They also impose awkward administrative
difficulties, requiring people to assess “additionality” of climate change
responses, and such judgements can at time appear rather arbitrary and costly (Valatin, 2012).
Random gifting
From time to
time the government has randomly gifted “thin air” credits, that represent no
environmental gain, to entities or people whom they wish to encourage or
mollify. These credits represent no
cleaning of the atmosphere and are of no greater value than Eastern European
“hot air credits”. Such gifts are very
tempting for a government because they enable a “reward” to be delivered
without any immediate impact on government accounts. Gifts include allocations of credits to a
power company for building a wind farm (the reward for a wind farm is power
generation that requires no credit surrenders, hence these credits were a
double payment), or an allocation of many millions of credits to pre-1990
forest owners to partially account for losses in land value (suffered when they
were forbidden to generate sequestration credits but were required to surrender
credits for emission of carbon stored in trees when land use changed). In this latter case any compensation should
have been in cash, but a more rational approach would have been to treat all
forest equally irrespective of the date of forest establishment. Gifting thin air credits floods the ETS with
credits that represent no environmental gain and so contributes to credit
currency inflation.
Recommendation:
Random gifting by government should be illegal.
Irrationality of grandfathered versus
forest-based credits
In a
well-functioning emissions trading scheme, polluters would have to submit
credits in order to be allowed to pollute, and they would purchase credits from
those who cleaned up their pollution. So if the cost of cleaning was
higher than the cost of reducing pollution in the first place then they'd
choose to reduce emissions. Either way the atmosphere would not receive any
more GHGs and purchasers of carbon credits could rightly call themselves
"greenhouse gas neutral".
However, that's not what's happening. If a polluter reduces their pollution below the cap then they can sell grandfathered credits. They also assert that purchasers of their credits can claim to be "greenhouse gas neutral". They are wrong.
There are many ways to explain why they are wrong. You could use stories, mathematics, graphs or even children's blocks. Let's use the latter.
Blocks below represent levels of greenhouse gas in the atmosphere and levels planned to be emitted by two polluters.
However, that's not what's happening. If a polluter reduces their pollution below the cap then they can sell grandfathered credits. They also assert that purchasers of their credits can claim to be "greenhouse gas neutral". They are wrong.
There are many ways to explain why they are wrong. You could use stories, mathematics, graphs or even children's blocks. Let's use the latter.
Blocks below represent levels of greenhouse gas in the atmosphere and levels planned to be emitted by two polluters.
Figure 1
Then polluter 2 opts to no longer pollute and has grandfathered carbon credits for sale. Polluter 1 purchases those credits and is allowed to pollute. The result is more greenhouse gas in the atmosphere, as shown below. Polluter 1 clearly cannot claim to be "greenhouse gas neutral".
Figure 2
So, what kinds of credits can confer greenhouse gas neutrality on a purchaser? Let's reach for the blocks again. In this case, we have the atmosphere, a potential polluter and someone who will take greenhouse gas from the atmosphere (maybe using new trees, a scrubber, or perhaps by seeding the ocean with iron to promote plankton); a sequesterer.
Figure 3
The sequesterer receives carbon credits for removing greenhouse gasses from the atmosphere. They are purchased by the polluter, who then goes ahead and pollutes, but the amount of pollution is exactly equal to the amount of sequestration and so the result is shown below:
Figure 4
Clearly, the atmosphere gains no new greenhouse gas and the polluter can now claim to be greenhouse gas neutral.
It is generally much cheaper to do nothing than to extract greenhouse gasses from the atmosphere. If we allow people to sell carbon credits for simply reducing outputs of greenhouse gas, we effectively pay them for nothing, and it takes much longer for emissions trading schemes to work because few will engage in activities that extract greenhouse gasses from the atmosphere.
A further problem with forestry in cap and trade schemes
Cap and
trade schemes are meant to work by limiting the availability of credits to a
known volume, but each credit earned by forestry potentially adds to the level
of the cap. One could argue that the cap applies to “net” rather than “gross”
GHG emissions, and so forest-based credits could be considered to be “net cap
neutral”, but this begs the question of how to deal with the fundamental
difference between forest-based credits and credits manufactured from thin air
by government, as outlined above. Our
current scheme is essentially irrational with respect to forest-based credits.
Some solutions
There are a
couple of ways to deal with this irrationality.
Option 1
Exclude
forest-based credits from the ETS and find other ways to encourage new forest
establishment, such as greatly expanded forestry encouragement grants. This
option would probably be unpopular with forest owners already engaged in
earning NZUs.
Option 2
Abandon the
idea of a cap and trade scheme, and redesign the scheme so that polluters who
purchase NZUs are truly GHG neutral. This
might be achieved if we:
·
Stop grandfathering credits
·
Have no random gifting of NZUs from Government
to industry
·
Apply the ETS equally to all sectors
·
Set emission reduction reduction targets each
year that stabilise the NZU price and allow us to meet international
commitments
·
Require surrenders only for “over target”
greenhouse gas emissions
·
Allow trading only between sequesterers and
emitters
o
If you overpollute you pay someone else to clean
up
·
Manage our domestic credits as a currency rather
than as a commodity
·
Plan to gradually reduce our NZU price as the
world solves the climate change problem
In this way
the “target” emission % of existing emissions becomes the cap, and reducing the
% gradually would see us meet our national targets in a planned fashion.
The second
option would be unpopular with carbon credit traders, but they contribute very
little to solving the problem of climate change.
Some other ETS issues
Auctioning of credits
Auctioning
credits made out of thin air that represent no environmental gain (see above),
will undermine forest-based credits that do represent environmental gain.
International credits
International
credit schemes vary hugely and have many of the same irrationalities as our old
ETS. So far allowing international credits in our scheme has been catastrophic,
and I have little confidence in our collective ability to distinguish between
bona fide and fraudulent credits. We
should not allow international credits in our domestic scheme.
The case for using forests as a short-term
mitigation option
The government
has initiated a “one billion tree” programme to jump start the planting of new
forests in New Zealand. New forests are sinks for CO2, while old
forests are reservoirs or even sources of CO2 emission. The means
that establishing new forests can only be a temporary solution to climate
change. The rationale for New Zealand’s ambition to plant new forests is
therefore to create sinks which would fill a gap in our carbon accounts during
the middle part of this century (assuming we wish to keep our commitment to GHG
neutrality by 2050) while we simultaneously adapt our economy to reduce gross
GHG emissions.
The gap in our accounts
In March
2017 Vivid Economics published a report commissioned by a cross-party group of
parliamentarians outlining alternatives for New Zealand’s responses to climate
change (Vivid Economics,
2017).
Several pathways to GHG neutrality were outlined in the paper, but the most feasible
one, called the “innovative scenario”, would get us to GHG neutrality by 2080
at the earliest unless forests were used to fill a large gap in net GHG emissions.
Evison & Mason (in prep) have identified a way to fill this gap using
forests as temporary sinks. The gap is
shown in grey in Figure 5 below. GHG
emission/year in millions of tonnes are on the y-axis and years are on the
x-axis. The blue line shows the innovative track of gross emissions, extended
to 2080, and the orange line is our desired pathway.
Figure 5
The area
under the grey line represents 1432 Mt of CO2-e.
Using an
estate simulator, a tree planting programme was designed that filled this gap,
using approximately 1.75 million ha (for reference, the area of New Zealand is
approximately 27 million ha). It involved establishing radiata pine, 75% of
which was assumed to be harvested periodically and 25% was permanent carbon
forest. The area was planted over a span of 28 years. The Figure below shows
the estimated impact of programme.
Figure 6 –
Sequestration impact of planting 1.75 M ha of radiata pine forest over 28 years
In Figure 6,
the red line shows the gap in our accounts, while the black line is the
sequestration of CO2 by the new forest.
By contrast,
if the 500,000 ha of new forest under the “billion trees” programme was
established in radiata pine, the sequestration effect is estimated to be as
shown in Figure 7 on the next page. Clearly 500,000 ha of new trees would not
be enough to fill the gap and new initiatives are required. As shown in Figure
8 on the next page, planting 50% of the new area in native forest and 50% in
radiata pine forest would not be as effective.
Figure 7 -
Sequestration impact of 500,000 ha of new radiata pine forest over 10 years
Figure 8 – Sequestration impact of planting 250,000 of pine and 250,000 ha of native forest over 10 years
The case for exotic tree species
Many imported species grow and
sequester CO2 much more rapidly than native species within the time
frames required to meet our target. Radiata pine has been chosen as an example
for the following reasons (although other species such as dryland eucalypts
might do the job equally well or even better in some cases):
1) It grows rapidly and sequesters C at
a much higher rate than native species. Between 2008 and 2012, our national
carbon accounts indicate that radiata pine planted after 1990 sequestered at an
average rate of 34 tonnes of CO2-e/ha/year, and rates might be even
higher with silvicultural regimes aimed at maximising value from sequestered
carbon credits. By contrast, estimated rates of sequestration for native
species are often below 10 tonnes of CO2-e/ha/year during the years
following forest establishment (Scott et al., 2000; Trotter et al., 2005), and the slower development of young
native stands would mean that they would take longer to begin any effective
sequestration. In older indigenous stand higher rates have been reported on
some sites, but not near the rates typical of radiata pine. To be fair, studies
of native forest sequestration are uncommon, but we can also get an idea of
relative sequestration rates by comparing the more numerous reports of growth
rates of stems of various species (Pardy, Bergin, & Kimberley, 1992;
Silvester & McGowan, 1999), and native species typically take
3-4 times longer to reach equivalent volumes of radiata pine plantations at
harvest.
2) We are experts at producing seedlings
for exotic species and they are cheap.
3) Radiata pine will grow on a wide
range of sites and we understand how to establish it on diverse sites, despite
its sensitivity to shade and frost.
4) Radiata pine is not a high country
wilding risk (Ledgard, 2008).
It is very intolerant of both shade and frost, and would only seed naturally
on moist lowland areas where adjacent land was not intensively grazed (which is
a rare condition in New Zealand). Our wilding species are commonly other, more
hardy imports, such a P. contorta, P.
ponderosa, P. nigra and Douglas fir. These wilding risk species should be
avoided in carbon forests.
5) On warm, moist sites (either medium
or high productivity categories), it would act as a nurse crop for native
forest, and the C reservoirs we establish would ultimately change to become
native forest so long as seed sources were available in the local vicinity
(Figure 9). Understoreys of native vegetation are common in plantations on such
sites (Brockerhoff, Ecroyd, Leckie, &
Kimberley, 2003; Ogden,
Braggins, Stretton, & Anderson, 1997). This issue has been much studied by
a PhD graduate from the School of forestry named Adam Forbes (Forbes, Norton, & Carswell, 2015a,
2015b, 2016). In order for native forest to
regenerate under pines local native seed sources are essential.
6) Studies suggest that radiata pine
will continue to sequester carbon for up to 100 years on some sites (Woollons & Manley, 2012), but we have assumed 60 in this
analysis. This means that the forests
would remain as sinks for some considerable time.
Figure 9 - Forest biomass dynamics
after introducing the exotic pine species Pinus
radiata to the native species pool. Dynamics are modeled for a site near
Christchurch, New Zealand. Species aboveground biomass is cumulative. "Kunzea and Leptospermum" include the early colonizing species K. ericoides and L. scoparium. "Others" include the species Griselinia lit- toralis, Pittosporum
eugenioides, Aristotelia serrata, Elaeocarpus hookerianus, Fuchsia ex-
corticata, Nothofagusfusca, and N.
solandri var. solandri Figure from Hall (2001).
Recommendation:
New Zealand policy should encourage the establishment of radiata pine and other
selected exotic species as permanent carbon forests, with the proviso that for
every 10 ha of exotic species, 1 ha of local native stands are either
identified or established to act as seed sources for the gradual succession to
native forest as carbon reservoirs.
Price ceiling
According to
Manley’s (2016) analysis a 50,000 ha/annum
new forest planting programme (anticipated in the “one billion tree” programme)
would require an NZU price of approximately $50. Moreover, radiata pine planted
and left on erosion-prone land would stabilise the land (Marden & Rowan, 1993), and would eventually revert
to native forest, so long as local seed sources were available (Forbes et al., 2015a, 2015b, 2016),
but this requires a credit price of at least $35 according to Manley. Setting a
price ceiling on “thin air” credits manufactured by government and that have no
environmental credibility, would reduce the likelihood that afforestation would
contribute to climate change mitigation.
Forest “averaging”
As we have
adopted the “averaging” proposal for forestry, then to be consistent those who
own pre-1990 forests should be liable for only the “average” C content of their
production forests when they change land use.
This would eventually remove the requirement for two categories of
forest land under the ETS.
Look-up tables for forest sequestration of
GHGs
Current
lookup tables are pessimistic for many exotic species while being optimistic
for the years immediately following planting of native species. This is
misleading people about the viability of meeting our international commitments
by planting slow-growing native species. The tables should be consistent across
species.
Harvested wood products
The benefits
of storing carbon in wood products should be equitably shared between growers
of forests and users of wood products, so that people are encouraged to use
wood instead of GHG-intensive alternatives.
Euan G Mason
Professor
University
of Canterbury
References
Alessi,
M., & Fujiwara, N. (2011). Study on
the Integrity of the Clean Development Mechanism.Centre for European Policy
Studies. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/linking/docs/ji_track_en.pdf
Forbes, A. S., Norton, D. A., & Carswell,
S. E. (2015b). Artificial canopy gaps accelerate restoration within an exotic
Pinus radiata plantation. Restoration
Ecology. https://doi.org/10.1111/rec.12313
1 comment:
My speaking notes:
I am Euan Mason and I'm here on behalf of future generations.
I support the zero carbon bill.
* Our target of net zero by 2050 is a good start.
* * I'd like to remind you that 280 ppm should be our ultimate goal.
* Having an independent climate change commission is great.
Target - GHG neutral by 2050
* The Globe study showed we could get to net zero by 2080.
* We can get there by 2050 only by reducing emissions and filling a gap in our accounts with new forests.
* * New forests are C sinks, old forests are C reservoirs.
Our 1 billion trees programme, as currently constituted, will not get us there.
* We need to rely on the Emission Trading Scheme (ETS).
Our ETS is not fit for purpose
* Imagine running a business with double entry accounts, with no requirement that balance sheets balance.
* Imagine that some sectors are taxed vastly more than others.
* This is our current ETS.
Methane is 84 times worse than CO2 on a 20 year horizon.
* It has an atmospheric half life of 7 years.
* All greenhouse gasses have half lives - examples (60-100 for CO2, 100 for N2O).
* What matters are increases in emissions leading to higher atmospheric concentrations being maintained.
* A different standard for methane makes no sense.
In short:
* ZCB is great
* The billion tree programme is a start but will have minimal impact
* Our ETS is illogical:
* * Proper accounting rules are needed.
* * All sectors should be treated equally.
We can get to our targets but we need to embrace change and rigour in our C accounts.
Post a Comment